Do company take-overs help or harm the economy?

21 September 2015 by in Business and finance, Nine visions of capitalism

By Charles Hampden-Turner, co-author of Nine visions of capitalism.

The City and Wall Street head the world in mergers, acquisitions and take-overs. The conventional wisdom is that if Company A has more money than Company Z then it should be allowed to take it over. This will help us all since the more successful companies are taking control of the less successful, the very rich are acquiring those of lesser means and therefore the whole economy improves. If you can convince shareholders that they can earn more when Company A takes over Company Z then this will put the target company under better management than before. Those with the most cash to spare are better by definition.

But is this so? Affluent economies are expensive places to make goods and services. Nearly all standard products are cheaper to produce elsewhere. The major exceptions to this rule are innovative products and services. If your product is original you have no competitors for several months or more and can charge for it what the market is prepared to pay. We in the West must innovate or die. There are signs that we are meeting this challenge to some extent but the question arises as to whether large companies that like to acquire others are as innovative as the companies they are gobbling up. The evidence is that most innovation comes from start-ups and relatively small companies. These are not only many times more creative but have much better labour relations, evoke more loyalty, spend more on training their people, think longer term, have better more trusting relationships and serve their customers and communities better. Gallup has found again and again that most citizens like small companies and trust them whereas up to 80% dislike large companies and distrust them. With size there comes bureaucracy, formality, rigidity and pre-programmed behaviour. To have these larger companies gobble up the small may be of very doubtful benefit to these smaller companies, to our economy and to our society.

In any event how can you ‘buy’, ‘own’ or ‘take over’ someone else’s genius? Hewlett Packard bought Autonomy for $1.7 billion, 79% above its market price and had to write down its value by $8.8 billion only months later. This is presently under furious litigation with accusations of deliberate misinformation filling press reports. We know nothing of these details and take sides with neither litigant. We would point out however that the value of information within the heads of genius founders is very difficult to know, hard to value properly and almost impossible to ‘acquire’. In the absence of a good and close relationship with that genius the value of intellectual property will melt away. The 79% premium over market price depended on the sharing of future strategies. How much s/he shares with you is largely optional and you may gain or lose you billions. You can legally mandate that the founder stays in your company for X years but not what will happen during that interval. In any case having received much of your money the genius cannot wait to found another start-up with the money made. Why benefit someone who claims to ‘own you’ and demands that you report to her/him on a regular basis?

Hostile takeovers are especially tricky. You can acquire the real estate, the inventory, the machinery, products in the pipeline, even signed contracts but what the company had in mind for the future could be its most valuable asset and in the face of hostility you may never learn it. You have the bits and pieces but not the values which held these together and gave the company direction. Apparently 79% of the value of Autonomy lay in its future and HP could not afford to fall out with those envisioning that future. Of course there is good reason why large companies are risk-shy. They have mountains of money to lose and any gains would be fractions of that mountain, while start-ups have almost nothing to lose but have bright horizons to explore. The shareholders in large corporations have little appetite for risk. Their pensions are at stake, while the ‘friends, families and fools’ rallying round the founder of a new company relish the wild ride and hope to found a dynasty.

There is also the question of time. A small, privately owned company is thinking how to support the children and grandchildren of its owning family. This is a time-horizon of twenty to forty years. An investment made now could greatly assist your grandchildren. In contrast shareholders in a publicly owned corporation now retain their shares for an average of six to eleven months. They are less investors than traders and will trade on the basis of the latest quarterly report. To reduce risk they have tiny fractions of their portfolios in any one company, care little about that company and may not even know that they ‘owned’ it for a few months last year! It follows that having a private company acquired by a public one might actually harm the economy and greatly shorten its view of the future.

Nearly all investments that aim to grow a company take many years to pay back. R&D, executive development, increased quality, new plant and equipment may justify themselves ten to twenty years hence. In contrast selling your HQ building and leasing it back, buying your own shares so that the price jumps, laying off researchers and cutting the training budget will all produce more money for shareholders this quarter and the longer term damage will not be manifest for a few years, that is after the present CEO retires. His pension may be tied to profits! The company has become a machine for maximizing shareholders’ take and resources are transferred from those who do the actual work to those who collect rents.

Companies who are on an acquisition spree either accumulate a cash mountain so that they can pounce swiftly or they borrow extensively so that their acquisition is heavily in debt. Both tactics may be detrimental the target company and to the economy. The cash mountain is not being re-invested and the debt burdens and even cripples an acquired company which must now concentrate on repayment, not innovation. The truth is that investing in R&D and in the training of your own employees makes you vulnerable to being taken-over. The raider says to your shareholders, ‘would you not like the money being spent on employees in your own pockets now?’ The answer is often ‘yes’ and since those to whom this offer is made include the most senior people in the target company who typically have share options, they have personal reasons for selling out their company!  No wonder that Professor Colin Mayer studying take-overs in the UK, especially that of Cadbury by Kraft, found that most of these acquired companies were well managed. It was precisely this which made them vulnerable. They were spending on the future and not today.

What seems to happen to companies who grow by acquisition is that they try to ‘buy the growth’ of others but do not grow organically themselves and the companies they acquire tend to stop growing and become ways of moving money to shareholders. No wonder that Virgin bought back its shares from the public, that Sainsbury’s fought off acquisition, that Hewlett Packard slashed its R&D spending much to the disgust of the founding family and that Chanel has refused all overtures. No wonder that Lidl and Asda are gaining at the expense of Tesco whose shareholders expect a larger slice of the supermarket pie. Privately held companies usually want to use money to create industry and make an industrious future for their families. Publicly held companies want to use industry to make money for their owners and see them enriched even at a cost of employees and customers.

Nine visions ADVERT

Paying for higher performance: The Great Delusion

10 September 2015 by in Business and finance, Nine visions of capitalism

By Charles Hampden-Turner, co-author of Nine visions of capitalism.

It sometimes seems that we have so fallen in love with a supreme fallacy that we cannot bear to look at the evidence against it. Our culture has convinced itself of a delusion and is unable to let go. Too many people have a stake in the fallacy. We are firm believers in pay-for-performance. This, we believe, is how markets operate and they are both wise in the allocation of resources and embodiments of freedom. The dream is that everyone gets what they deserve and prices reach their “right” level. There are some obvious difficulties. Why, for example, is China growing three times faster than Britain or America when they have a fraction of our incentives? Why is not the USA leaving all nations in the dust behind it spurred by its massive pay-offs for performance? Why did the best paid sectors of our economy, the banks, let us down so comprehensively, both practically and ethically? Why are we growing more slowly than in past decades when rewards were less? Something is obviously wrong.

Pay-for-performance has some obvious attractions as a belief system. It justifies the gains of the already rich. They are assumed to be economic wizards and exponents of private enterprise and removing any of their gains through taxation is seen as near-blasphemous. They will stop working! Economists love the idea because money is the independent variable of their discipline which they wish to explain everything. They dread having to defer to psychology or other rival disciplines. Since money can buy all things those who have it want it to buy all people in addition. It is a heady prospect. Those trying to maintain authority see payments as a tool to punish those who defy them and reward those who behave themselves. P for p is essential to maintaining social order.

So what is wrong? We all need money to live so that surely we will meet the conditions under which we are paid? What complicates the issue is that some motives are extrinsic – our need for money, praise, encouragement, the trappings of power and some are intrinsic – our need to create and innovate, our pride in a job well done, our sense of professionalism, our need to be appreciated even loved. These two sources of motivation may impede each other as we shall see.
The research on this topic is extremely one-sided and unambiguous. There are by now scores of experiments and follow-up tests but the results point only one way. Teams or individuals offered money incentives do worse than teams offered no money at all. There is only one exception to this rule. In tasks requiring no judgement, skill or problem-solving ability where the work is routine and mechanical, incentivized teams do better. In all tasks requiring even as modicum of skill and ingenuity they do worse.

Pay for higher performance: the great delusionIn a world getting more and more complex by the day this finding has devastating significance for any advanced economy. Is there an alternative? If pay makes no difference why do more competent receive higher pay? The answer is that we have got the sequence wrong. It is less that extra payment gains higher performance but that higher performance however motivated gains better pay. We excel for the sake of excelling and for the delight of expressing ourselves and thereby earn additional reward. What pleases us about our performance pleases others.
The classic case is the Candle Experiment more than eighty years old. Teams are asked to light a candle, attach it to the wall and make sure the melting wax does not fall on the floor. They are provided with a candle, matches and cardboard box of thumb-tacks. What makes this task not simply mechanical is realizing that the box is more than a container for the tacks but a crucial element in any solution. (You tack the box to the wall and the floor of the box to the candle and then light it.)

All teams solve the problem in less than three or four minutes, but those offered money take substantially longer More recently the money offered poor Indian villagers was two to three months wages and these eager members took even longer than the unpaid! This experiment has been modified and repeated with more elaborate tests of creativity substituted for the candle, but the findings hold. Offering money is counter-productive.

Why would this be the case? Daniel Pink has suggested that money rewards narrow perception. Money distracts the team members from a careful and thorough examination of the problem at hand. Any problem or complexity needs to be pondered and we often need to bring to the solution something regarded as peripheral – like the box in which the thumb tacks came. Any team in a hurry to get the money on offer is likely to try short cuts and the most direct route to tackling the problem. It is likely to fall back on routine coping skills. Apart from these experiments there are a large number of unintended consequences which follow upon pay for performance which render it ineffective and in some cases disastrous. Given the vast amount of bonus payments lavished on bankers and other executives, this may give us a clue as to why in so many cases their performance has been sub-standard and why fines for major banks in the latest scandal have topped 5 billion pounds. Here there is room for just a dozen of these unintended consequences set out in detail by Alfie Kohn.

  1. Performance is being defined by those in authority. This means it is not being defined by the employee her/himself or by the customer for that service but by what top managers’ demands. If authorities demand that customers buy swaps as a condition for taking out loans or insure themselves against a loss for which the bank not they are liable, then this gets done whether customers want or need it or whether it is ethically acceptable. The employee’s judgment and conscience are overridden.
  2. It assumes that senior managers know precisely what needs to be done, how hard this and what premium it deserves. In fact senior managers are a further from the coal face than anyone else and seldom know such details with any accuracy. A task that was once difficult may become easy with enough practice. Employees have varied skills and what burdens one may be easy for another. The environment and customer demands out there keep changing and with this what needs to be done and the relative importance of each job.
  3. It tends to harm creativity, innovation and problem solving. This is because finding a problem and solving it has no rewards attached to it. Top management does not know that the problem exists! As for a creative or innovative solution this has no known payment because senior managers had no idea that it was possible or that someone might do it. But all customary and routine tasks are rewarded so that p-for-p high-lights the conforming and punishes the original. If you do something new, however effective it is, you risk that your paymasters do not understand it , appreciate it and will refuse to pay for it.
  4. It distracts employees from giving customers what they want and what they are asking for. You pressure customers into accepting what has been incentivized and not what they really need. What is most profitable for the company and gets rewarded is not what the customer really wanted, can afford or is in his own best interests. The seller cannot put the customer first and foremost since the incentive skews his judgement and gets in the way.
  5. Employees respond to p for p by gaming-the-game. Pay for performance is a game and so employees feel justified in distorting it for their own purposes. Some tasks will be over-rewarded and some under-rewarded. Employees work this out and concentrate their energies on getting the most money for the least work and easiest tasks. Tasks that have not been adequately paid do not get done however serious the consequences for customers or the organization. Instead of doing what needs to be done employees do what is best rewarded.
  6. Employees may stop helping each other. In such a system rewards go to the person who receives help not the person who gives help. Why help anyone else when only that person gains from it exclusively? The other will complete the task and get the reward for your assistance. It essentially punishes helping behaviour by the giving the money to the person helped. It is possible to give a bonus to the whole team and this is to be recommended, but then that team is unlikely to get assistance from another team.
  7. Incentives tend to rob activities of their meaning. Children given 50 cents each time they fastened their seat-belts in an automobile, stopped fastening them when the payments stopped. They had missed the whole point that they should protect themselves if not for their own sakes then for their parents who had raised them. How much should be pay a nurse who has extracted glass fragments from the face of a crash victim and has had to tell her parents she will be scarred? Would $50 dollars cover it, or a t-shirt with a heart on it? The very question insults her. She did not choose her vocation to make money but to heal others. Teachers find intrinsic pleasure in teaching but markets make them pay for this by awarding them commensurately less.
  8. Bonuses render effective supervision of a subordinate very hard. What every supervisor has to do is the support the performer while critiquing the performance. You need to encourage the performer and make sure s/he keeps trying. On the other hand you need the actual performance to improve. Criticize too much and you will discourage. Praise too much and the supervisee may relax efforts. The message has to be mixed and the communication subtle. “I think so highly of you that I think you can do even better.” Either giving a large bonus or withholding it will entirely wreck this communication. It is altogether too crude. If you cost your subordinate her planned vacation, no way is she going to trust you again. If you give her the money she will forget the rest.
  9. Employees are disempowered in contrast to those in authority. The problem with pay-for-performance is that it gets subtracted from straight salary. No one is going to pay you more than they have contracted to do. This means that a proportion of your salary can be clawed back if the boss is not pleased with what you have done. If you receive a salary the boss has to trust you to give value. If you receive p for p you have to trust the boss to pay up and not withhold what you believe you have earned. It gives power to employers and takes power from the employed. No wonder it is popular with employers and some politicians!
  10. Employees retaliate against p for p by deliberately restricting output. Employees have a strong dislike of “rate busters”. This is someone who works so hard and quickly that management will base a new incentive structure on his level of output. By working “too effectively” the amount of work required for a given incentive is raised and everyone must work harder for the same amount of money. To stop rate-busters from working “too hard” an entire group of workers may agree to restrict their output and sanction anyone who threatens this norm. The output is fixed at a level they will not show anyone up or expose them to penalties. Better tools and improved ways of working may actually be hidden from management scrutiny lest these lead standards to be revised upwards. Instead they will be deployed in secret to resist pressure and buy leisure time. This leads us to the eleventh problem.
  11. The negative effect on social and technological change in the workplace. Once the status quo is tied to how much money people get for various jobs the employees are likely to resist change. Those who have found a relatively easy job that pays well will be especially resistant. New technologies may mean that what each task “deserves” will need to be re-assessed and several “good little earners” will be vanish. The new technology may be implemented grudgingly at a fraction of its real potential in the hope that management will revert.

Finally pay for performance tends to lower the esteem in which people hold themselves and each other. If only your performance is worth anything to the corporation then by implication you, as a person, are worth almost nothing and are readily substitutable by a more energetic person. You have been hired for what you can do. Many of the early banking scandals originated from those who were on “commission only”. If management cares not a jot for you but only for what you produce, then this same attitude tends to be visited by you on the customer. You do not care what she/he wants or if she can afford it, the sale is worth so much and you are determined to get it for yourself. The person dissolves into the task and is nothing but that task. If the person cannot perform then get lost. “It is not the bum territory, but the bum in the territory.”

The company holds the individual responsible for inferior results, not itself. However poor the leadership, inadequate the supervision, the training given, the instructions or the tools provided it is always the performers fault. The person alone is responsible which lets their managers and supervisors off the hook. P for P pretends that the individual is un-related and where this is not insisted upon s/he will blame others.

It is at least probable that money is a hygiene factor, the word coined by Frederick Hertzberg and denotes factors which hurt by their absence but do not motivate by their presence. For the absence of hygiene can kill people but fails to motivate them positively. Cleaner bathrooms do not mobilize energy, but stop it from dwindling. Similarly money is of near-obsessive concern where people feel they lack it. Tens of thousands may strike. Whole industries can buckle. Militant organizations may be unleashed, even a communist party. But where people are paid fairly and reliably the concern with money gives way to intrinsic motivations and joy of being productive and innovative. This is the desirable end.

Nine visions ADVERT

Nine visions of capitalism by Charles Hampden-Turner and Fons Trompenaars

7 September 2015 by in Book publishing, Business and finance, Nine visions of capitalism

9781908984401

Capitalism in crisis: top culture management gurus map the route to a fairer global economy

Capitalism has been in a state of crisis for nearly a hundred years. The effects of the stock market crash of 1929 were felt well into the 1950s. The turbulence in international currency markets in the late 1960s, which sparked worldwide street protests in 1968, was unresolved until the mid-1980s. And the avalanche of financial crises that followed the failure of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 is still falling on businesses, consumers and communities around the world. In the face of such evidence it would be easy to think that capitalism is a doomed system.

However in Nine visions of capitalism: unlocking the meanings of wealth creation authors Charles Hampden-Turner and Fons Trompenaars suggest otherwise. Capitalism does have a future, they say, but only if the standard Anglo-American model of capitalism is radically transformed. As the authors point out, creating wealth is much more than simply making money. They say, “A community is only better off when it creates wealth through the transformation of money into products and services and the transformation of these back into money via revenue received.” The current model of capitalism has led to a situation where the net worth of the world’s top 10 billionaires stands at over $500 billion, enough to end world poverty instantly twice over. But the global economy is not richer for the presence of billionaires if the money in their pockets has simply been transferred from those of other people.

So how can this failing model be fixed? Hampden-Turner and Trompenaars argue that accommodating diversity is a pre-requisite for the reinvention of wealth creation. China’s spectacular growth, the dynamism and flexibility of the Mittelstand of German-speaking economies, Singapore’s hybridization of East and West, the world’s vibrant immigrant communities and the drive for renewable energy offer different aspects of an authoritative and challenging blueprint for the  future of capitalism. Finally, the authors draw on examples of innovation in capitalism such as the Conscious Capitalism movement in the US, the Cambridge Phenomenon in the UK and the Global Alliance for Banking on Values, which has members from Mongolia to Patagonia as well as the US and UK, to demonstrate what can be done to reinvigorate tired models, and provide a realistic, practical and powerful transformation agenda for the global economy.

About the authors
Management philosopher Charles Hampden-Turner was Senior Research Associate at the Judge Business School at the University of Cambridge. The creator of Dilemma Theory and co-founder and Director of Research and Development at the Trompenaars Hampden-Turner Group in Amsterdam, he was Goh Tjoei Kok Distinguished Visiting Professor to Nanyang Technological University in Singapore in 2002–3 and Hutchinson Visiting Scholar to China in 2004. He is a past winner of the Douglas Mc Gregor Memorial Award and has received Guggenheim and Rockefeller fellowships. Fons Trompenaars is an organizational theorist, management consultant and bestselling author known globally for the development of the Trompenaars’ model of national culture differences. He was awarded the International Professional Practice Area Research Award by the American Society for Training and Development and Business magazine ranked him as one of the world’s top five management consultants. In 2013 he was ranked in the Thinkers50 of the world’s most influential management thinkers. He is the author or co-author of numerous books including Riding the Waves of Culture and 100+ Management Models.

Nine visions ADVERT

Making money is not a reliable guide to creating wealth

1 September 2015 by in Business and finance, Nine visions of capitalism

By Charles Hampden-Turner, co-author of Nine visions of capitalism.

Unhappy is the economy which cannot distinguish the making of money from the creation of wealth for these are not the same. While creating wealth includes the making of money, the latter is a more narrow activity which can and does in many cases exclude the creation of wealth. Indeed it may even destroy wealth on an epic scale as occurred in 2008. This happens when money is made by taking it away from other people and/or appropriating this from Nature’s bounty. Profits can be made by plundering other people and the planet. So what is the crucial distinction?

The distinction we must bear in mind and was pointed out in the nineteen eighties by Lester Thurow and more recently by Gideon Rachman, is between the zero-sum game or system of competing and the positive-sum systems of wealth creation. In a zero-sum world all gains come from other people or at the expense of the environment. All resources are finite or scarce as economists still teach us, so that what one person gets another must forgo. Alternative value can be extracted from Nature’s bounty, leaving the rest of us poorer for this. Inequality escalates and as the song of the ‘roaring twenties’ put it, “The rich get rich and the poor get poorer, in the meantime, in between time, ain’t we go fun!” Making money by exploiting others creates no wealth. The others are soon too poor to buy very much. Pay-day loans were almost certainly wealth destroying as is loan-sharking in general.

The City

So-called casino capitalism is very much a zero-sum game. Roughly half of all financial advisers are going to score below the Dow Jones average. This is not because they are stupid. Were they twice as clever this would still be their fate, since the average is the zero-sum of all their efforts which cancel each other out. Indeed there is a small overall loss since those running the casino need to be paid.

What then is a positive-sum game? This is where relationships between people generate more wealth than they began with. There is a surplus over and above the cost of what they generated which the parties share. The better wages and the higher share price put money into people’s pockets which they spend anew. Also the value delivered by the supplier may be hugely increased by the use to which the customer puts it. Both live in a world of abundance and this moulds their characters. We will cite examples of each.

In the case of Josiah Wedgewood, the world’s first tycoon, he took loads of red Staffordshire mud and with the help of pottery skills, new instruments he had designed, heat, paint and glaze he made a Portland Vase, Jasperware and other pots. Even in the currency of the times these were at least one hundred times more valuable than their ingredients and graced the royal tables of Europe. His medallion of a kneeling slave in chains culminated in the abolition of the slave trade after his death and it well symbolizes the two faces of capitalism in the distinctions which follow.

Or consider a more modern example. For a decade or more there have been more microchips than people in the world. It must be at least two or three times by now.  A chip installed in your automobile can inflate an airbag before your child’s head can hit your windscreen in a crash. It can unlock doors so you can escape or rescuers can reach you and it sends out signals of your plight. In such cases it saves lives, reduces insurance premiums and enriches all concerned. Yet bits of metal and silicon sand cost next to nothing. You have put human intelligence and purpose into the chip and this comprises its value. Intelligent design followed by intelligent manufacture saves what is most precious to us, the lives we hold dear plus our own. As East Asians like to say, microchips are “the rice of industry”. They feed other businesses and give thousands of products meaning and direction.

This leads us to consider business-to-business wealth creation where the supply of one device allows a second task to be accomplished. Suppose we make number-controlled cardigan knitting machines. Once installed, these knit 2,000 cardigans in one day with sizes altered in seconds. The supplier creates wealth by the method already described. The whole machine is of far more value than its components, but his customer creates wealth by way of the machine functioning. Indeed the machine by itself is valueless. But the garments created at an attractive price make both money and wealth. Supplier and customer have engendered wealth between them, despite their different aims and purposes. In a further example, Rolls Royce aero-engines produce power-by-the-hour to convey people to far destinations. Wealth lies in what they do, not in the engine itself. Contracts even specify this.

We are now in a position to contrast Zero-sum money making with Positive-sum wealth creation.

Zero-sum money making Positive-sum wealth creation
Money is made by direct manipulation of the individual for his exclusive purposes. This money derives from other people Money is made indirectly by first benefitting a customer who then reciprocates by bestowing more money upon you.

We are getting ever more individualist, so much so that relying on the favour of other people is deemed unreliable. To be totally independent you need you need to outsmart them by taking their money. “Never give a sucker an even break” is our watch-word and we need “to make a quick buck” which is not possible when you rely on another’s gratitude. The real individualist acts unilaterally whether people like it or not. Our wits entitle us to this.

In contrast all genuine wealth creation inheres within relationships, so that the Chinese word for “rich” is “well connected” and guanxi or relationship is their chief business value. The whole must be more than its parts and design and manufacturing are all-important to being productive. Between us we create more than we started with and trust is vital. A research group at MIT studied what motivated 800 creators of open-source software and make this available to all. The originators said it was a gift by them to the online community and they were repaid in many ways. Such action triggers the productive efforts of others on a wide scale.

Making money is via transactions in which one person receives money from another and gets goods or services back. The parties compete to get more from others at the least expense to themselves Wealth is created by transformation of money into goods and services & their transformation back to money when sales are made. This is the source of the surplus value generated

If the above statements are correct then we need to ask whether banks and financial institutions create wealth at all. They would appear to be sterile by dealing exclusively in money or “financial products” as they like to call them, but there is no transformation and no wealth creation. No two coins or notes cohabiting ever produced a third coin or ever will. So long as we stay with money there is endemic scarcity as economists teach, not the abundance of related brain cells and their associated meanings. Whatever trades’ unions receive shareholders and managers must forgo and the strategy of the latter is to pay as little as possible to remain competitive on costs. Taking money and creating a product and/or service from this is a transformation from currency to valued things and services and then back to money revenues when the sale is made. It is these conversions or metamorphoses from one state to another that generate wealth.

On the other hand we need banks to advance loans to industry so there is little doubt that they facilitate wealth creation by the real economy. What this means is that banks create no wealth on their own but make it possible for industry effect transformations. In short the role of banks is to serve industry and not principally themselves. Bets made in the world casino are zero-sum, with some of the big boys able to skew the markets in their favour by the sheer size of their wager and by using their clients’ money.

Banks do “make money” in one sense. They leverage funds and lend out as much as twenty to thirty times what they hold in assets. This conjuring trick should not be confused with genuine wealth creation, because where asset prices collapse leverage goes into reverse and banks LOSE twenty to thirty times as much. This is how trillions disappeared in 2008, an error for which we have been paying ever since. Banks need asset prices to hold up and only genuine wealth creation can do this. They create derivatives from these assets and then derivatives from those derivatives in a veritable house of cards. But unless they serve industry better these foundations will remain unstable, as were their subprime mortgages and their liars’ loans.

By distributing money to worthy persons and institutions banks aim to make the most profit with the least possible risk plus the highest level of collateral. Banks are simply one more industry and should compete with best of them The receivers of the banks’ money are the real contributors and wealth creators, whose products are risky, uncertain and hard to assess, so banks avoid them. Banks are NOT simply one more industry and competing with customers hurts all.

One reason bankers pay themselves so much is that vast sums pass through their hands for which they are responsible. Surely that deserves compensation? But the real reason they pay themselves so much is that they can. As distributors, the money reaches them first and what they skim off is up to their own discretion. Of course, industries will then lack funds with what amounts to a private tax levied across the board. Less money reaches the genuine contributors. Banks are not just another industry but a means of distributing money to industry and the tricks they use have abused this powerful position

But even these diminished amounts go to the wrong people. Catering to the already wealthy is a highly conservative process. They have much to lose and too little to gain. But even worse is funnelling money to the housing market. This is low risk, high collateral because most people pay off their mortgages and houses can be repossessed if interest is not paid. But it is also very low productivity. The house holder sits tight among his/her own possessions and waits for the property to increase in value. It often beats working! Two groups of American economists examining international comparisons have shown that faster expansion of the financial sectors triggers slower growth in the real economies. Talent and resources are attracted away from contributors towards distributors. The success of the City may be a doubtful blessing. UK industry has been in steady decline for more than 150 years. Manufacturing is down to 10% of the economy and productivity is faltering, not enough of the money is reaching the genuine contributors.                                    

Conclusion

Wealth-creation is a social, transformative, positive-sum activity. It needs at least two persons to create wealth and this is generated by the relationship between them. Merely making money may be sterile and speculative. The customer may have no choice but to accept your terms and this too is corrupting for the supplier and impoverishing for the buyer. The making money by itself can and sometimes does weaken the economy as a whole. All speculative activities are zero-sum with losers matched to winners. There is evidence that uncertain money rewards can be addictive and where capitalism imitates a casino we are all ill-served, even where the finest minds are attracted to a speculative enterprise, half will lose. We need to identify genuine contributors and get the money to where it can be used to create wealth. Banking is a service to industry and to people and it competes with its customers to the detriment of us all.

Nine visions ADVERT

China’s stocks fall putting global economy on edge

24 August 2015 by in Business and finance, Current events, Nine visions of capitalism

This morning the FTSE plunged as the Chinese economy fell, putting investors around the world on a knife edge. Not since 2007 has there been such a drastic drop in global stock prices.

For many years, since the fall of Mao, the Chinese economy has flourished. It has been a great hybrid of ‘capitalism and communism’ as suggested in Charles Hampden-Turner and Fons Trompenaars’ riveting new book, Nine visions of capitalism. Look at the objects on your desk. Many of them will have been made in China. Over the past few decades, labour and manufacturing have been outsourced to China. Why? Well, quite simply, profit margin. For example, it is cheaper to catch fish in the North Atlantic, export it to China to be packaged and then ship it back to Britain than it is to package it in the UK. Clearly this is not an environmentally friendly way to do business, but from a purely capitalist perspective, it is effective.

China FTSE

Why is labour so much cheaper in China? Well, more people are willing to work for lower-paid jobs. With greater competition for jobs, companies can keep wages low. If you don’t want to work for a pitiful pay cheque, then someone else will. Mao’s regime forced millions into dire poverty and some are only now beginning to recover from this. Let’s, for now, put our assumptions about the working conditions aside.

Though definitely not a wholly capitalist country the People’s Republic of China has benefited from Western economic influence. While we outsource labour and other primary services to China, China in turn benefits from what Western capitalism can provide. Capitalism has allowed China to become one of the biggest economies in the world, while still claiming to be outside the capitalist bubble.

So, back to today. Over the past fortnight, the value of the yuan has been depreciating. Since then, trillions of dollars have been wiped from the FTSE. What does this all mean for the future of the economy? Perhaps China’s financial stability was poorer than anticipated. It would seem likely that the cheap labour and services that the West has been benefiting from for many years will now cost more. Trading with China will become a more costly endeavour and this could fundamentally change the face of our manufacturing and primary services.

Once again, our eyes are focused on those on Wall Street who are moving the intricate cogs that support the global economy. To the uninitiated every-person on the street, what goes on is something of a mystery. We are aware of the importance of the FTSE and the NYSE as well as how they have an important effect on the global economy. Like a heart monitor in an intensive care unit, the peaks and troughs of the FTSE index mean little to those who are not trained to recognise what it all means. But we can all imagine that the £91bn that was wiped off the FTSE today is not positive for the global economy.

China is undoubtedly a superpower with great influence. Western domination is being gradually usurped by China’s infiltration of other economies. Like dominoes, when one is affected it runs the risk of knocking down the others. We are making slow but progressive steps out of the recession that began in 2008. The memories, however, are still fresh in the minds of all who were affected, many of whom lost their homes, their jobs and their savings.

However this latest crisis develops the 2008 recession taught a valuable lesson: capitalism affects everyone under its umbrella, and often, it is those that need help most who get hit the worst when times are hard.

Nine visions ADVERT

Capitalist leaders are called to account

17 August 2015 by in Business and finance, Current events, Nine visions of capitalism

Earlier this month, emerging political candidate Bernie Sanders called out the top CEOs in America and asked them to account for their actions. It’s a familiar story, the Fat Cats on Wall Street engage in illegal activity, make exorbitant amounts of money, and then let other people deal with the consequences (if you’ve seen The Wolf of Wall Street, you’ll know what we’re talking about). Why does this matter? We’re all aware that those with the biggest bonuses are not the ones feeling the pinch of the recession that we’re only just recovering from. Well, with Greece still in crisis, the UK threatening to leave the EU, and the American election on the horizon, these are very real issues that we need to grapple with.

In his letter to The Wall Street Journal, Sanders said that the ‘Wall Street leaders whose recklessness and illegal behavior caused this terrible recession are now lecturing the American people on the need for courage to deal with the nation’s finances and deficit crisis.’ In a two-pronged attack on the wealthiest people in America, Sanders published a report that shows how various CEOs and corporations have managed to evade $34.5 billion in tax. These people claim to want to close the deficit but are actively contributing to the problem. If the average person avoids tax, it probably won’t make that much of a difference to the government. However, to reach $34.5 billion in unpaid (or avoided) tax it would require a significant proportion of the population of America just refusing to play by the law. If it was the average man on the street, he’d go to jail. But because the top players on Wall Street maintain so much power, it would seem that they are beyond the law. It is time that we stopped turning a blind eye to this sort of avoidance. The capitalists that determine, by and large, our financial stability, are the ones who should be an example for the benefits of capitalism. America is perhaps the biggest capitalist country in the world, and yet it would appear that, rather than show how capitalism can be beneficial to the economy and help those all the way at the bottom of the pyramid, it is leading the way in demonstrating the worst aspects of capitalism: greed and the misuse of power.

Wall Street

When companies such as Apple, Google and Microsoft are now richer than the US government, one looks to them to set a positive example of how capitalism can benefit not just those who work for the corporations, but the government to whom they pay tax. These are global corporations but they all began in Silicon Valley. They are the very epitome of American capitalism at its best, highlighting how small start ups can become global brands. However, these companies should also be a marker for how all companies in the capitalist food chain can not only be successful, but create wealth and grow the economy. Not all companies will be as successful as these, but even small companies can take lessons from conscious capitalism. Charles Hampden-Turner and Fons Trompenaars in their new book, Nine visions of capitalism suggest that ‘Wealth is created when values are joined by meta-values, when for example workers receive higher wages for being more productive so there is money or value for everyone. Customers provide more revenue that is shared between employees and investors. Wealth is also created when products do not die and go to waste but become a cradle for another product.’

The iPod is an excellent example of a product which has evolved and grown, making way for better and smarter technology while maintaining the integrity of the original. So Apple is leading the way. You only have to look around you and you won’t be far away from an Apple product. This is demonstrative of capitalism being beneficial to the customer as well as the company. There are many people who are loyal to the Apple brand. However, with great wealth comes great responsibility. Apple and its chiefs must demonstrate a conscience in a world that is powered by wealth. Back in June, Taylor Swift called Apple to account when they said the they would not pay artists in the first few months of their music streaming service, ‘We don’t ask you for free iPhones. Please don’t ask us to provide you with our music for no compensation’, she wrote in an open letter to the company. Recognising the backlash that this would cause, Apple quickly did a 180 on their policy and announced that they would pay royalties. Case closed. Nevertheless, Swift proved that large companies are not infallible and that it pays to be seen as a company that is doing good.

Capitalism and the companies that contribute to the growth of wealth are not infallible, but they are incredibly wealthy and powerful. It will take more than Taylor Swift to bring down Wall Street. Yet the conscious capitalism movement is growing and it’s people like Swift and Sanders who have the platform to call those to account who should be doing more to help the economy grow rather than contribute to the deficit. It is incredibly unlikely that the next President of the United States will be the CEO of Coca-Cola or Microsoft, but their influence is not to be ignored. Those with such influence and power should work alongside governments to help find a solution to the economic crisis. Paying taxes will be a drop in the ocean compared to what they stand to lose if the house of cards that these people live in decides to topple.

Nine visions ADVERT